Modern Portfolio Theory, introduced by Harry Markowitz in 1952, provides a mean-variance framework for building portfolios that maximize expected return for a chosen level of risk—or equivalently, minimize risk for a chosen return. Risk is proxied by the variance (or standard deviation) of returns, and the critical insight is that an asset's desirability depends not on its own risk-return profile but on how it co-moves with every other asset in the portfolio.
Risk-averse investors: prefer lower variance for equal expected return.
Returns are jointly distributed with finite means and variances; investors care only about those first two moments.
Single-period horizon with homogeneous expectations.
Frictionless markets (no taxes, transaction costs, or limits on shorting).
These idealized conditions let the optimization collapse to simple quadratic programming.
Let
: portfolio weights s.t.
: expected returns
: covariance matrix
Solving either version generates one point on the efficient frontier—the set of portfolios delivering the highest return for each risk level.
Plotting expected return (vertical) against portfolio volatility (horizontal) yields a Markowitz bullet; its upper-left boundary is the efficient frontier. Introducing a risk-free asset spins a straight Capital Allocation Line (CAL) from the risk-free rate tangent to the frontier; its tangency portfolio maximizes the Sharpe ratio and underpins the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM).
Loading chart data...
Because portfolio variance includes covariances, combining imperfectly correlated assets lowers overall volatility—allowing higher expected return for the same risk. This mathematical formalization of "don't put all your eggs in one basket" remains the most cited justification for global multi-asset investing.
The power of diversification is one of the few "free lunches" in finance, allowing investors to reduce risk without necessarily sacrificing return. This principle is mathematically demonstrated in the portfolio variance formula:
When correlation () between assets is less than 1, the portfolio variance is less than the weighted average of individual variances, creating the diversification benefit.
Issue | Response / Extension |
---|---|
Non-normal returns (skew, kurtosis) | Post-Modern Portfolio Theory; higher-moment optimizers |
Parameter uncertainty | Bayesian & resampled MVO; robust optimization |
Single factor | CAPM, then multi-factor (Fama–French, Carhart) |
Estimation error in covariances | Shrinkage estimators (Ledoit-Wolf)—used in our backend |
Markowitz, H. (1952). "Portfolio Selection." The Journal of Finance, 7(1), 77-91.Access the paper
Markowitz, H. (1959). Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. John Wiley & Sons.