The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) is a cornerstone of modern financial theory developed independently by William Sharpe, John Lintner, and Jan Mossin in the 1960s, building on Harry Markowitz's work on portfolio theory. For this contribution, Sharpe shared the 1990 Nobel Prize in Economics with Markowitz and Merton Miller.
CAPM provides a framework to understand the relationship between systematic risk and expected return for assets, particularly stocks. It's widely used in finance for pricing risky securities, generating expected returns, and evaluating investment performance. The model introduces the concept that investors need to be compensated in two ways: the time value of money and risk.
Despite its theoretical elegance and practical utility, CAPM has been challenged by empirical tests, leading to the development of more complex models. Nevertheless, it remains widely taught and used due to its simplicity and powerful insights into the nature of risk and return.
CAPM is often described as the finance world's "one-factor model." At its core, it presents a revolutionary idea: investors are only compensated for taking systematic (market-wide) risk, not for specific risks that can be eliminated through diversification.
In essence, CAPM distinguishes between two types of risk:
• Cannot be eliminated through diversification
• Affects the entire market (e.g., economic cycles, interest rates)
• Investors are rewarded with a risk premium for bearing this risk
• Measured by beta (β)
• Can be eliminated through diversification
• Specific to individual stocks or sectors
• No expected premium for bearing this risk
• Examples: company scandals, management changes, product failures
This distinction leads to the powerful conclusion that diversification is the "free lunch" of investing—it eliminates specific risks without reducing expected returns. What remains is systematic risk, which becomes the only relevant risk factor in pricing assets.
The CAPM equation elegantly expresses the expected return of an asset as a function of the risk-free rate plus a risk premium:
Term | Meaning | Practical Interpretation |
---|---|---|
Expected return of asset/portfolio i | The return investors should require for investing in the asset | |
Risk-free rate | Typically yields from T-bills, government securities, or overnight repo rates | |
Expected return of the market portfolio | Return of a broad market index like NIFTY 50 or S&P 500 | |
Asset's market beta (sensitivity to market movements) | Measure of systematic risk; how much the asset's returns move with the market | |
Market risk premium | Extra return investors expect for taking on market risk rather than investing in risk-free assets |
This straight-line relationship between beta and expected return is known as the Security Market Line (SML). It represents the central insight of CAPM: higher beta (more systematic risk) should lead to higher expected returns.
Beta is calculated as:
Or equivalently:
Where:
The classical CAPM rests on several key assumptions that simplify the complexities of real markets:
Real financial markets violate these assumptions to varying degrees, which has led to the development of extensions like the Black CAPM (zero-beta CAPM), multi-factor models (Fama-French), and models incorporating liquidity premiums.
The derivation of CAPM follows from Markowitz's Modern Portfolio Theory and reveals why only systematic risk matters:
From these insights, we can derive the CAPM equation for any asset :
This shows that expected excess return is proportional to covariance with the market, not to the asset's total variance. This is the fundamental insight of CAPM—only systematic risk is priced in equilibrium.
In practice, CAPM parameters are typically estimated using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression:
Where:
In matrix form, the OLS estimator is , which produces:
Component | Typical Data Source |
---|---|
Risk-free rate () | 3-month T-bill or 10-year G-Sec yield (annualized) |
Market return () | Broad index (NIFTY 50, S&P 500, MSCI World, etc.) |
Return frequency | Daily or monthly; market and asset returns should use the same frequency |
Our portfolio optimization backend automatically:
The Security Market Line (SML) is a graphical representation of the CAPM relationship. It plots expected excess returns against beta:
Asset A: β=0.8, E(R)=10% (Undervalued)
Asset B: β=1.2, E(R)=7% (Overvalued)
Asset C: β=1.5, E(R)=10.5% (Correctly Priced)
The SML has several key interpretations:
Correctly priced assets should fall exactly on the SML, indicating they offer returns commensurate with their systematic risk.
Assets plotting above the SML have positive alpha (α), suggesting they're undervalued and offer excess returns beyond what their systematic risk would predict.
Assets plotting below the SML have negative alpha, suggesting they're overpriced and don't adequately compensate investors for the systematic risk taken.
Use Case | How CAPM Helps |
---|---|
Cost of equity (DCF, WACC) | , where MRP is the Market Risk Premium. This estimates the required return for equity investors. |
Performance attribution | Decompose portfolio return into alpha (skill) + beta × market (exposure to market movements). |
Risk budgeting / hedging | Size positions in a portfolio to achieve a desired target beta, managing overall market exposure. |
Factor models baseline | CAPM serves as the "1-factor" benchmark before adding size, value, momentum, and other factors. |
Asset allocation | Helps determine expected returns for different asset classes based on their systematic risk. |
While elegant in theory, CAPM has several empirical challenges. Various extensions have been developed to address these limitations:
Limitation | Extension/Solution |
---|---|
Beta instability — Betas tend to vary over time | Rolling betas, regime-switching models, Kalman filter estimation |
Non-normal returns — Asset returns often exhibit fat tails and skewness | Downside beta, conditional value-at-risk (CVaR) models, quantile regressions |
Multiple priced risks — Market beta alone doesn't explain all variation in returns | Fama-French 3/5-factor models, Carhart 4-factor model, APT (Arbitrage Pricing Theory) |
No risk-free borrowing — Not all investors can borrow at the risk-free rate | Black CAPM (Zero-beta CAPM) replaces the risk-free rate with a zero-beta portfolio |
Liquidity concerns — CAPM doesn't account for transaction costs or liquidity differences | Liquidity-adjusted CAPM, Acharya-Pedersen model |
Despite these limitations, CAPM remains a fundamental model in finance due to its simplicity, intuitive appeal, and practical insights into the relationship between risk and return.